Books

BUSINESS IN THE GILDED AGE: THE CONSERVATIVES' BALANCE SHEET

July 1952 L. G. Hines
Books
BUSINESS IN THE GILDED AGE: THE CONSERVATIVES' BALANCE SHEET
July 1952 L. G. Hines

byEdward C. Kirkland '16. University of Wisconsin Press, 1952; 59 pp.; $1.50.

Edward C. Kirkland, professor of history in Bowdoin College, delivered the Knapp History Lectures as visiting professor at the University of Wisconsin during the second semester of the 1950-51 academic year. Business inthe Gilded Age is the product of this assignm ent and a preview of a forthcoming revaluation by Professor Kirkland of the period between the Civil War and the beginning of the twentieth century. The Knapp Lectures are thumbnail sketches of the views of three diverse commentators of this period: Charles Francis Adams Jr., the descendant of Presidents and the brother of the famous Henry Adams; Edwin Lawrence Godkin, journalist and moralist; and Andrew Carnegie, both actor and critic during America's gilded age of business.

Although Charles Adams led a varied lifehe was a gifted amateur historian, an overseer of Harvard, and the president of the Union Pacific Railroad—Professor Kirkland has chosen to identify Adams as a (government) bureaucrat because of his work with the Massachusetts Railroad Commission during its formative years. As either a government or business bureaucrat, however, Adams' appraisal of business behavior was essentially pragmatic, and he was generally unfavorably impressed with what he saw. For example, "Honor for its own sake and good faith apart from self-interest are, in a business point of view, symptoms of youth and defective education." But Adams was no reformer; his views on the public were only slightly less sardonic, and Professor Kirkland finds that Adams was led in disillusionment to adopt a grim and amoral survival-of-the-fittest approach to social affairs.

Edwin Godkin, founder of The Nation and one of the most influential journalists of his era, was both more sanguine concerning contemporary business practices and somewhat more hopeful of their improvement than Adams. Godkin viewed the keen individualism and materialism of early industrial America as the inevitable result of its youthfulness, but he had little good to say of businessmen, frequently considering them cultural illiterates whose hands could often be found in the public's pockets. At the same time he found in the "principle of competition" the basic natural law "by which Providence secures the progress of the human race." During the later period of his life, however, Godkin became embittered by such events as the silver movement, the Spanish-American War, and the idle and wanton rich. Democracy, he concluded, was a failure, and virtually all moral standards were debased.

Andrew Carnegie was both an industrialist and a frequent commentator on public and business affairs. It is in the latter capacity that Carnegie is of interest to Professor Kirkland, and it is of course Carnegie who finds in business the appropriate challenge to intelligent and idealistic youth. But in the end Carnegie joined Adams and Godkin at least partially finding the quest for money both ignoble and sordid, and accepted what he believed to be the millionaire's obligation of dispensing his money for the good of the people.

Professor Kirkland's preview achieves the distinction of being both entertaining and informative, and one looks forward to the completion of his study.